Senate Health Committee Issues Testimony From Northwestern University Professor (Part 1 of 2)
* * *
In contrast to all other developed countries,
Nowhere is the benefit of economic markets for healthcare clearer than in the development of novel pharmaceutical products. Over the past several decades, the world has benefitted from remarkable progress in the ability to address a wide range of medical conditions using pharmaceutical innovations. Patients with medical conditions that previously amounted to death sentences have either been completely cured or now live with manageable chronic conditions, those suffering from a multitude of cancers have seen their lives meaningfully extended, and cardiovascular mortality has remarkable declined.
Few, if any, of these advancements came to market without the involvement of private firms investing capital in a market-based setting. This demonstrates the centrality of private markets and capital to our system of drug development. Given this fact, our policies should focus on how best to support and organize efficient markets for drug development and commercialization. Such markets require, among other features, a clear and identifiable set of rules governing how firms will earn potential returns from successful innovations and a trustworthy regulatory state to enforce those rules.
Today's hearing focuses on the question of whether
Understanding the potentially broader ramifications of today's hearing requires acknowledging the basic and incontrovertible fact that new pharmaceutical products are developed in an expensive and risky ecosystem that involves a variety of institutions and firms. Each type of firm plays a different role along the complex path from early-stage research to proof of concept to clinical trials and ultimately, if successful, to commercialization. The variety of organizations at each step of this process are motivated by different goals and each provides their own unique contribution to this development process. Therefore, optimal policies must carefully understand and respect the incentives of these firms.
While early-stage research is more often funded by public actors (i.e. governments or nonprofit organizations), this is only the first step in the long path from bench to bedside. Navigating the rest of this path requires private firms to invest large amounts of fixed and sunk capital with little certainty of a profitable return. Firms are willing to make these investments based on risk adjusted models of the profitability of their investments -- models that require making strong predictions and assumptions about market conditions many years in the future.
These private firms can only attract the capital required for drug development if they can generate a return for their investors that is sufficiently attractive compared to other non-pharmaceutical investment options. This is the fundamental economic reality at the center of the drug development process. If we choose to ignore this fact in favor specious arguments and grandstanding about pharmaceutical greed, it is incontrovertible that we will forfeit access to some future medical innovations - which will likely decrease health and welfare.
While uncertainty around the scientific and commercial prospects of potential products makes all pharmaceutical investments inherently risky, we should strive to reduce additional uncertainty stemming from the policy environment. This is particularly true for policies that alter the rules of the game only after firms make their large, fixed, and sunk investments to develop new products. Sunk investments are expenditures that cannot be recouped by firms after they are made. For example, once a firm spends money to run a clinical trial it is unable to get that money back if the trial fails or the product is not commercially successful. To avoid being stuck in unprofitable situations, before making such an investment firms must be careful and diligent in attempting to predict how the market might subsequently evolve.
If firms believe policymakers will expropriate the gains from investments that are deemed "too successful," they will almost certainly be less willing to make the same portfolio of investments as they make today. We must always remember that it is this portfolio approach, where a small number of large successful investments support a larger number of failed projects, that serves as the foundation of drug development. If we desire to have firms to continue to willingly make the large capital investments necessary to promote health and economic welfare, we must sustain a system where firms trust that the government will be a reliable counterparty that establishes the rules of the game and then abides by those rules. This is true even when it means allowing firms to capture large windfalls from products that generate massive amounts of value and health for society.
The potential for sowing distrust in the process exists across a wide variety of dimensions. Consider the question of whether or not
We provided these public funds to decrease a private firm's risk of product development and increase the speed of these products to patients. Absent government support, it is unclear whether private capital markets would have provided a similar amount of investment on a similarly short time frame. When these transfers occurred in early 2020, private firms faced risks from developing vaccines along two dimensions. First, they faced commercial risk, i.e. the possibility that by the time a vaccine was developed and manufactured in sufficient quantities the pandemic would be "over" and demand for the product would be quite low (or at least lower than would have been necessary to justify investing in the vaccine in the first place). This is a common concern of firms reacting to a novel pandemic with an uncertain duration. To address this first type of risk, the
The second form of funding was for clinical trials. This type of funding was intended to shield firms such as
This swift approach was exactly our goal as a nation. It is my understanding from publicly available documents and news coverage that there were no constraints placed on
Therefore,
* * *
1 Notably,
* * *
2 It is possible that such constraints exist in parts of the contract that have not been disclosed, but I have not seen any evidence of this fact.
* * *
The potential broader loss of trust is only exacerbated by recent commentary and policy proposals regarding expansions to price setting power for pharmaceuticals granted to the
A degradation of trust in government institutions is not an abstract concern. A fundamental tenet of investments in new pharmaceutical products is that a robust, fair, and trustworthy regulatory state will enforce existing market rules and regulations. Beyond the methods of determining market prices, these regulations include those surrounding valuable institutions such as patents and other forms of intellectual property protection. Firms require these government provided protections because the very heart of the innovative process for new drugs represents a market failure that must be addressed. The failure results from the fact that the scientific advancements generated by firms in the development of innovative pharmaceutical products are essentially a public good, i.e. the knowledge generated by these investments is effectively non-rival and non-excludable.
* * *
5 It is my understanding that this initial funding agreement did contain a large number of restrictions on how funds could be used, so it seems even more reasonable that firm believed it would represent a complete set of future constraints.
7 https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/biden-2024-budget-proposal-drug-prices/644674/
* * *
* * *
8 Rational firms realize that, absent some form of government intervention, they will be unlikely to capture the value generated by the large investments necessary to bring a product to market. This results in an economic phenomenon known as "hold up" whereby firms, absent some form of intellectual property protection to protect their eventual returns are unwilling to make value-creating investments in the first place.
* * *
To address this initial market failure, governments offer various forms of intellectual property protection. Through patents or other forms of market exclusivity, governments arm firms with time-limited periods of enhanced market power that allow them to capture the value created by their innovative products. During this time period, the high prices curtail some access to valuable medicines.9 However, this reduced access today is deliberately traded off against the development of new products in the future. These new products provide access to patients for whom there would otherwise be no treatment - a situation could be seen as a more severe access problem than patient access restrictions due to higher prices. After all, prices can always be negotiated downward while there is no amount of negotiation that will grant access to treatments that don't currently exist. Such treatments will only come from new investments in technologies that will improve patient health.
In this way, policies governing drug development exemplify the old adage that there is no proverbial "free lunch." Instead, policies governing the development of pharmaceutical products involve trading off the static inefficiency of reduced access to products today in order to create the dynamic efficiency of the increased development of new products in the future. The goal is in balancing the magnitudes of these two effects. To the extent the value created by the new products exceeds the welfare losses created by the high prices (and resulting decreased quantity sold), the periods of market exclusivity are welfare-enhancing. Importantly, this could be true even if the prices today are quite high.10 In fact, for some products treating small patient 8 The degree to which this is fully a public good depends on how much information can be gleaned from the actual product, the regulatory filings, and the published research. For example, small molecule products can be more easily reverse-engineered and therefore absent intellectual property protections are relatively easier to copy. Biologic products, however, have a more complex production process and therefore copying the technology is easier than making the product de novo but harder than for a small molecule product.
* * *
9 The amount of reduced access is complicated by the presence of health insurance which mitigates the output restrictions by lower prices (Lakdawalla and Sood, 2013).
10 This is particularly true because the impact of high prices on quantity is far more complicated in a world of widely available health insurance. Those who are insured may not suffer as much decreased access as they would in a market without third party payment. However, those for whom drugs do not exist certainly will not access a treatment at any price.
* * *
This tradeoff is a root cause of much of the controversy for prescription drugs because the reduced access today involves some number of readily identifiable individuals who are unable to access existing and potentially life-saving medications because of price.11 Unsurprisingly, this particular form of a lack of access garners large amounts of press and political attention. However, it is always critical to remember a perhaps far greater access problem for patients suffering from conditions for which no treatment options exist at all. For these individuals, there is no price at which a treatment is available. These patients will gain access in the future only as a result of the dynamic incentives created by intellectual property protection. As we consider the optimality of policies governing the pharmaceutical market, we must balance the oft-discussed need for access to existing products with the less-discussed lack of access from the absence of effective treatments.
To be clear, it is perfectly acceptable to make reasoned and considered alterations to our existing regulatory frameworks. However, we should do so with careful deliberation and respect for the underlying economic facts. We must be honest and recognize that such changes will result in a lower level of investment in innovation, however, we may be willing to forgo such innovation in return for lower prices. That is the a debate that we should be having.
Regardless of the policy we pick, it is critical that we make large changes before firms sink capital at risk into drug development. If instead, we attempt to expropriate the value of successful products from the firms that invested to create them we will ultimately chill some amount of future investment.
Making changes to the explicit and implicit contracts that currently govern the drug development process will have long run impacts on future innovations. For example, some activists and policymakers have put forward theories that the government, by virtue of its investments in basic scientific research, have broad abilities to seize intellectual property. Putting aside whether such "march-in" rights actually exist in response to high prices (which is a legal question beyond my expertise) it is clear that such rights have never been exercised in that way in the modern biopharmaceutical market. Therefore, this would represent a fundamental shift in the beliefs of firms about the value of intellectual property - beliefs that serve as the foundation of modern drug development. This would have widespread ramifications on how people and firms engage with government-funded science and the ability of such public investments in basic science to improve the availability of treatments in the market. It is hard to imagine that firms making decisions about commercializing products using
* * *
11 Garthwaite, Craig, and
* * *
That said, the time period where firms are granted market power over their innovations must be time-limited. Our goal is not to provide firms with unending returns on their investments but to balance the incentives necessary to attract private capital to these markets with access to medical innovations. Striking this balance requires the government to establish clear and firm rules about how long such a time period will last and then ensure we have strong and robust competition when periods of market exclusivity expire.
In my testimony below I provide details on policy solutions that will facilitate competition for products as their intellectual property expires - an area that is a critical component of our system. When considering optimal policies to promote competition and generic (or biosimilar) entry, it is important to remember that our goal is to decide on the preferred degree of intellectual property protection required to encourage the desired level and type of future innovation. After setting these parameters, it is incumbent on regulators to monitor and enforce these systems. This includes providing the necessary structures for strong competition between therapeutic substitutes during periods of exclusivity and the development of robust generic competition beginning immediately at the end of the exclusivity period.
Ultimately, firms will attempt to optimally respond to any incentives governments create - and therefore a well-functioning healthcare market requires policies that embrace economic reality rather than hope for a preferred outcome. In particular, we must ensure that our policy infrastructure matches the existing economic conditions created by the more complex and expensive medications we are currently developing. Much of the successful infrastructure that we have built over time for post-exclusivity competition was designed for the small molecule generic market. Small molecule generic products are exact bioequivalent copies of approved innovative medicines. As a result, we as a society are often more comfortable with competition promoting regulations such as automatic substitution that swiftly and effectively move almost the entire market to generic products after patent expiration. Large molecule (or biologic) products, however, are too complicated to create exact copies and therefore "generic" competitors come to market as "biosimilars" - a designation that means they are not automatically substituted.12 This introduces important nuance for how we think about competition and entry after patent expiration. It also leads to an inherently more complex patenting environment that makes questions about entry timing more difficult.
* * *
12 While there is a pathway for biosimilars to be labeled as interchangeable, this greatly increases the costs of development and to date has been rarely used by new entrants.
* * *
For example, biologic products are more often used to treat a wider variety of conditions and indications than many historical small molecule products. These broader uses for a product are socially valuable and are developed based on meaningful investments by firms in clinical trial evidence. As a society we must support the use of existing products for as many conditions as is appropriate. However, we must also develop and enforce policies that promote competition at the indication level which balances incentives for developing new uses for existing drugs with the need for time limitations for market power over a firm's initial innovations.
Firms should be rewarded for making the investments necessary to prove their products would be clinically effective against additional indications. However, as a society we must balance these additional financial rewards for firms with our desire to support competition in the market. Specifically, we must be wary that new indications could be exploited to thwart potential entry into the market by new firms attempting to market a generic version to treat only the original indications. If this were to occur, an innovative firm could capture an inappropriately large amount of the economic surplus created by the ability of their product to treat the original medical condition (as opposed to value created by the new indication).
To address this concern, one area where we require greater clarity, guidance, and potentially legislation is around the ability of new entrants to implement a so-called "skinny label" strategy. Under such a strategy, firms could introduce generic or biosimilar competitors to the market for single indications that are not protected by patents or FDA exclusivity. However, the new entrant would be prohibited from marketing this product for any indications that were still protected by a patent. As I discuss below, it is imperative we create a clear and appropriate pathway for competitors to enter at the indication level even if patents exist for other indications.
Emerging questions around skinny labels and market entry are examples of the inherent complexities created by the more sophisticated products and processes involved in modern drug development. These complexities also result in a wide array of patents for the same product. While many cite the existence of such a large number of patents as prima facie evidence of "gaming" and anti-competitive behavior by firms, the story is actually more complicated. Increasingly complex pharmaceutical products likely give rise to a far more complicated patenting environment. Given the sophistication of production methods and the increasing ability of products to be used for a variety of indications, successful products are now surrounded by meaningfully large patent estates. There is no question that this makes it harder for potential competitors to enter. There is, however, an open question as to whether large numbers of patents represent the large amount of intellectual property required to develop these types of products or a deliberate strategy by firms to deter entry. Of course, there is no single broad answer to this question and any policy solutions must respect the nuance of intellectual property protection and the resulting incentives in this area. That said, I outline several policy solutions below intended to both increase the rigor of patent review (and therefore the strength of the resulting patents) and better regulate the process of generic and biosimilar entry.
Beyond questions around patents and labeling strategies, it is also clear that the lack of bioequivalent "generic" products for biologics creates difficulties for market entry. In particular, the lack of an exact, substitutable copy (an interchangeable biologic) creates some hesitancy for physicians to move patients off of existing reference products on which the patient is medically stable. This hesitancy likely results from the fact that achieving medical stability is often a process that can take many months or years of identifying the correct medication and dose for the patient. As a result, biosimilar entrants are often competing for only a portion of the existing market (either patients who are not medically stable or newly diagnosed patients who have not yet started a treatment regime). As I discuss below, this inability to rapidly access the entire market, combined with features of our existing pricing and rebate system can make it difficult (or impossible) for biosimilar firms to enter and gain meaningful market share. In particular, an existing system where firms often make rebates contingent (all or in part) on competitors not being "on formulary" can meaningfully benefit incumbents at the expense of new market entrants.13 Such formulary contracts that "reference a rival product" could dissuade entry and artificially extend the incumbent's market position for particular types of biologic products. In the same way that rules around generic entry differ for small and large molecule products, it may be necessary to create different regulations for how formularies are constructed for biologic products.
In addition to concerns about formulary placement, our existing system of physician reimbursement for many biologic products creates incentives for physicians to continue to use more expensive products. This is particularly true under Medicare Part B but also pervades portions of the commercial market - where reimbursements often follow the structure (but not the absolute level) of Medicare payments. Reforms to Medicare Part B reimbursements could both promote entry and decrease artificial incentives to increase prices in the private market - both of which should be policy goals.
Finally, the difficulties for competitive markets created by more complex products are not limited to biologics. While we traditionally believe the small molecule generic market works well, this is primarily true with the more common large markets with numerous patients available to multiple firms. The success of the system supporting generic entry is far less clear when the size of the market is small and therefore struggles to support multiple competitors. In such cases, single firms can acquire all existing rights to market a drug, raise prices, and still face little entry because there are insufficient incentives for new firms to enter. In this way, the generic market would function as if a firm continued to enjoy some form of intellectual property protection. While this problem is limited to a relatively small number of products today, an increase in "precision medicine" where even small molecule products can be targeted at very small populations means this concern will only grow in prominence over time. Therefore, it is important to address these questions today before they become a dominant market feature with powerful political supporters.
* * *
13 It is important to note that the source of such exclusionary contracts is unclear. It is quite possible, and even likely, that firms are encouraged by PBMs to make an offer that would grant them the entire market. This could be optimal for each PBM even if it is not optimal for the entire market.
* * *
As you can see, my testimony today focuses on promoting competition in pharmaceutical markets - with a particular focus on competition after regulatory exclusivity. That said, it is always important to remember that the goal of government policy in this area is to balance the incentives for innovation with a patient's access to value-creating products. Others have proposed more drastic exercises of government power in order to simply reduce prices today. This is often driven by inappropriate promises that these price decreases will come without cost. However, that is not the case. When considering the potential patient access benefits of such proposals to artificially reduce prices, we must be comprehensive in our analysis and consider both the degree of improved access today and the ability of the market to continue to provide access in the future to patients who currently lack existing treatments.
I understand it is tempting to cave to the crass political calculus that purports to increase access in a visible way today and obscures the potential long-term costs of such decisions. After all, once we observe the magnitude of those costs most elected officials making these decisions will have moved on to other careers. But the goal of policy is to carefully weigh those future costs and not believe snake oil promises that expropriating value from firms today can cure all of our ills with no side effects. In the testimony below I provide more details about policies that will balance these various forces to ideally enhance health and economic welfare.
I. The Tradeoff Between Access and Innovation in the Modern Pharmaceutical Market
It is not surprising that attention to high healthcare prices has focused so heavily on the pharmaceutical sector.14 Patented prescription drugs are sold for many multiples of the marginal cost of production and, as a result, firms appear to simply be profiteering at the expense of patients. Complaints that high prices are primarily about corporate greed ignore that they are the result of deliberate government policies intended to provide the necessary incentives for the continued development of innovative products. By granting intellectual property protection, governments allow innovative firms to earn positive economic profits for a 14 In thinking about this attention, we should note that pharmaceuticals make up at most 20 percent of healthcare spending.
* * *
While the logic of trading off some amount of access today in order to gain access tomorrow is clear, the parameters of the length and breadth of this tradeoff are policy decisions for which there is no definitive economic answer. These policy parameters reflect the relative value society places on lost access today and potential welfare gains from future innovation. They also reflect the degree to which high prices today may not lead to a correspondingly large reduction in access because of the market-expanding features of health insurance.15 Understanding the nature of the trade-off and determining the appropriate policy parameters in the contemporary market requires understanding a bit more about the modern pharmaceutical development process. New products come to market through the partnership of a variety of actors in the value chain. This includes basic science done for understanding the nature of disease, early-stage pre-clinical research to develop a proof of concept, and then an arduous process of navigating the regulatory process to prove that a product is ultimately safe and efficacious. Each stage of this process represents meaningful risk and firms will only undertake each successive step in the development process if the expected net returns are sufficiently attractive compared to the next best use of the invested funds.
Certainly, the development process begins with basic science research - a meaningful portion of which is financed by government entities such as the
* * *
15 It should be noted that these high drug costs could impact premiums and the ability to buy insurance. Heavily-insured markets can create an incentive for higher drug prices and could result in decreasing welfare in situations where insurance is sold for generic and branded products as a bundle.
16
17
* * *
Understanding the pitfalls of proposals to strengthen the role of the
That said, without significant additional investments in drug development, this government-funded basic science research would not result in treatments that address unmet needs in the market and increase economic welfare. In the current market, these additional investments are provided by private firms that undertake additional research and development to commercialize the
I.B. The Decentralization of Early-Stage Drug Development
Proponents of strict price regulation point to the fact that the savings from such efforts could be redirected back to the
* * *
18
* * *
While it is possible the
The fact that so much early-stage innovation is done by small private firms that do not ultimately commercialize the product has led many to claim that regulators have the freedom to decrease prices without harming innovation. After all, since the firms currently selling the product didn't actually undertake the costly investments in early-stage R&D, those early innovative activities are not driven by the eventual profits of these more established firms. This couldn't be further from the truth. The ultimate goal of the providers of private risk capital for early stage firms (e.g. venture capital investors) is a profitable "exit" for their funds. This traditionally happens in the form of an acquisition, though increasingly we are also seeing early-stage biotechnology firms going public through an initial public offering (although this trend has reversed in recent years given existing market conditions). The financial terms of these eventual exits are dictated by the potential revenues of the product in the market and thus would be affected by regulated prices that decrease average returns.
In this way, the access and innovation tradeoff is perhaps even greater in the modern world of venture capital backed early stage drug development. This private funding is inherently mercenary in nature and in search of the highest returns. If potential returns from biotech investments fall, investors will simply redirect their funds from the pharmaceutical sector towards the next best option.19 In this way, policies which decrease the potential profits will lower investments in early-stage investments and the resulting increase in profits. While we might think that the
* * *
19 While it is true that there are a number of venture capital firms that focus entirely on the biopharmaceutical sector, they are primarily investing other people's funds and those investors are targeting areas of the economy that provide the greatest returns.
* * *
Again, we may find it optimal to limit the flow of innovation in exchange for greater access to the smaller number of products. However, this must be a reasoned calculation and not one based on the false belief that the efforts of even a better-funded
II. The role of government in limiting welfare losses during period of market exclusivity
For the reasons discussed above, determining the parameters of the access and innovation tradeoff is difficult. That said, there is clearly a role for the government in attempting to limit (to the extent possible) the loss of welfare that occurs during periods of market exclusivity. This can be done both by ensuring the existence of robust competition among therapeutic substitutes and supporting the operation of well-functioning insurance markets. There are four areas where the government could do more in these areas: (1) promoting competition at the indication level when products can treat multiple conditions; (2) supporting a robust system for evaluating patents; (3) creating a modern infrastructure for regulating competition between biosimilars and reference products; and (4) developing strong incentives for price competition between products in government insurance programs.
II.A. Promoting Competition at the Indication Level when Multiple Indications are Present
When products are able to treat multiple conditions the time period for the market entry of competing generic or biosimilar products can become muddled. Innovative products often contain various types of patents and exclusivity related to the underlying molecule, its production, and its method of use. Even in the situation where all of these are valid, it can be difficult for firms to navigate this large set of patents (a concern that I also discuss in the following section).
We want to provide the incentives for firms to find multiple uses for existing products. After all, society has already invested meaningful resources to show that such products are safe and provide efficacy in at least one condition. This includes both clinical trial evidence but also valuable real world evidence about safety from patient populations that are often much larger than those in the original trials.
That said, we also do not want these additional indications to shield firms from appropriate generic competition for the original uses of these drugs. For this reason, existing regulations allow generic firms to enter with a "skinny label" that only allows them to market the product for indications that no longer have patent protection or other forms of exclusivity. However, existing regulations also require that the label for a generic product matches the existing reference product's label. Recently, a federal court ruled that certain information that is required to be on the label could be viewed as an inducement to infringe on the reference products method of use patents.20 This ruling creates an untenable tension in current law where we want generic firms to enter with a skinny label, but existing regulatory requirements could apparently require such firms to include information on their label that would result in them infringing on some of the patents held by the manufacturers of the reference products. Regardless of future court decisions in this area, it is imperative that
II.B. Negotiations over patent infringement
Market exclusivity is governed by a variety of governmental institutions. Central to this system are the intellectual property protections provided by patents. Patents offer protection for firms developing novel products. During the time period of patent protection, firms are safe from competition arising from a new entrant selling an exact copy of their innovative product. After patents expire, the intention is for other firms to swiftly enter the market and sell copies of the patented product, with the resulting competition lowering prices and increasing access.
Obviously, there is a clear role for government involvement in this area. After all, the initial granting of patents and other forms of intellectual property protection is solely a government action. Governments also regulate the challenges to such patents and the process by which competitors enter the market as exclusivity expires.
Potential entrants observe the rules created by governments and weigh the potential costs and benefits of attempting to enter into competition with a branded product. Increasingly, this includes navigating a myriad of patents related to the underlying pharmaceutical product, the various uses of the product, and its production process. Given the requirement that patents be narrow and specific to a particular invention, modern complex products are often covered by a wide range of patents. Critics claim this large number of patents reflects an attempt by innovative firms to create a "patent thicket" that raises the costs of entry. These critics believe that rather than reflecting intellectual property, the large number of patents is solely intended to create a costly entry barrier that decreases the number of potential entrants and extends the length of market exclusivity. Given this concern, some critics have gone as far as to suggest that each branded product should be limited to a single patent.21
* * *
20 https://www.supremecourt.gov/DocketPDF/22/22-37/222237/20220429174452402_Scanned%20Application.pdf
* * *
While it is surely true that some firms engage in such a "thicketing" strategy to deter entry, the mere existence of even a very large number of patents is not, on its own, evidence of a nefarious strategy. As the complexity of the production process increases, it is reasonable to assume that these processes will also involve the creation of important and necessary intellectual property. All else held equal, this would result in a greater number of patents per product.
Beyond the complexity of production, pharmaceutical products are increasingly used to treat multiple conditions. Discovering potential new uses for these existing drugs requires additional expenditures on scientific discovery and clinical trials. The incentives to invest in those activities stems from the ability to appropriate some of the value created. Given there are great benefits to society from firms developing new uses for existing products, we should encourage firms to investigate whether products which have already been determined to be safe could be used for additional indications. A system that limits the number of patents that can exist for a product would diminish the financial incentives for firms to invest resources to determine these new uses.
That said, the existence of large numbers of patents creates a more difficult path for generic and biosimilar entry. The heart of this concern, however, should not be about the number of patents pertaining to a particular product but instead about the underlying validity of those patents. Ultimately, this is a question about the efficacy and rigor of the patent approval process undertaken by the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). If the PTO is granting a large number of relatively weak patents to firms that are deterring entry, this is something that should be addressed directly. It could be that this is the result of the growth in demand for patents on potential new innovations outstripping the resources available to the PTO. Academic research has shown that resource constraints affect the accuracy of patent examiners, with more time-constrained examiners issuing patents that were more likely to be later invalidated.22 Rather than making sweeping rules about the number of patents, policymakers should more directly examine increased resources in an efficiently run PTO.
* * *
21
22 Frakes MD, Wasserman MF. Investing in Ex Ante Regulation: Evidence from Pharmaceutical Patent Examination.
* * *
One potential model to provide greater resources for the PTO is a process similar to the Prescription Drug User Fee Act (PDUFA) which provides vital additional resources to the FDA that flex with the level of regulatory demand. It is possible that pharmaceutical patents could be assessed additional fees that could be used to increase resources in this area.
The large number of patents creates a further concern about negotiations between branded firms and potential entrants about the timing and manner of entry. Under our existing system, an economically meaningful fraction of generic entrants come to the market by challenging some of the underlying patents of the branded product. Given the potential cost and complexity of these lawsuits, these firms often settle on a negotiated date of entry. These negotiated dates are invariably before the formal end of every related patent but after the date indicated by the earliest patent affecting the product in question. There are valid concerns that such negotiations are a ruse to extend the exclusivity period for branded firms. Effectively, the concern is that the brand and potential entrant are colluding to split the surplus resulting from the lack of competition. Such concerns are correctly heightened when branded firms transfer something of value to the potential entrant. While the oft-discussed Actavis decision stops firms from transferring money in exchange for delayed entry, that has not eliminated concerns that settlements detailing entry could be a source of concern.
That said, such settlements are an expected result of a system where we rely on potential entrants to use "Paragraph IV" challenges to effectively police the validity of patents granted by the PTO. Litigation is costly, uncertain, and distracting to the main business activities of firms. For this reason, firms in all markets often attempt to settle lawsuits out of court rather than taking them to trial. Rather than attempt to cast all settlements as attempts to manipulate the market, I would encourage policymakers to revisit the policies that govern such challenges. Over time, Paragraph IV challenges under Hatch-Waxman have become a very common feature of the entry of new products. Even unmeritorious challenges are expensive for the system. It is possible that various features of the market, including but not limited to the 180 day exclusivity for the first-to-file generic firm and the 30 month stay for patent challenges, may be an inefficient means of policing and operating an intellectual property protection system.
One potential avenue to consider is the Reforming Evergreening and Manipulation that Extends Drug Years (REMEDY) Act of 2019. This proposed act would eliminate the 30-month delay for generic entry that is automatically triggered when a patent is challenged. Importantly, this would only apply to patents that are not the main product patent. Without the automatic 30 day stay, a generic firm would be free to enter "at risk," i.e. if they are later found to be infringing on a valid patent they would owe damages to the patent holder. The economic incentives here would result in firms only entering when they believe that the patent is truly weak, i.e. firms would be unlikely to enter at risk against strong patents because they would be afraid of having to pay damages. In that way this would eliminate the protections for weak patents that are currently created by automatic 30 month stay.
II.C. Biosimilar Adoption and Rebates
While rebates serve a vital function in drug price negotiations, there are also situations where the structure of the rebate contract can potentially create a barrier to entry for new competing products. For example, rebate contracts sometimes reference rival products, particularly with respect to a rival's placement on the formulary. Depending on the economic context, such rival-referencing contracts could be either anti-competitive or pro-competitive. For example, a manufacturer may offer larger rebates if its product is the only one in a therapeutic area on the preferred tiers of the formulary. If there are many potential products that are competitors for the entire market, such a contract could be efficient. In fact, these types of contracts are at the heart of the PBM strategy. In describing his strategy, the Chief Medical Officer of Express Scripts said, "So we went to the companies, and we told them, we're going to be pitting you all against each other. Who is going to give use the best price? If you give us the best price, we will move the market share to you. We will move it effectively. We'll exclude the other products."23 Since 2012, there has been marked growth in the use of these exclusion lists.
In situations where manufacturers are competing for access to the PBM's entire patient population, these types of contracts can be pro-competitive, leading to large discounts and increased welfare. However, for some types of products, large portions of the market are not truly contestable, i.e., the PBM will not be able to effectively move a fraction of the patients to the low-price product. For example, patients who are currently using a biologic product may be unlikely to be willing to switch to a competing biosimilar at almost any price. In addition, PBMs might find that payers would not be happy with strategies that forced their patients to move across biologic products in this manner.24 In a situation where a new entrant cannot effectively compete rapidly for a large fraction of patients, a rebate contract for the incumbent product that is contingent on the absence of the rival entrant on the formulary can serve as an almost impenetrable barrier to entry. This situation is sometimes referred to as a rebate "wall" or "trap." Effectively, the new entrant finds that it cannot offer the PBM a large enough rebate on its products (which represent a relatively small share of sales) to overcome the lost rebate dollars from the incumbent (which represents a majority of the market). In such a situation, the new entrant would find it quite hard to ever gain meaningful market share. Perhaps more concerning, realizing the existence of these rival-referencing contracts, potential biosimilar manufacturers may never choose to attempt to create products in the first place. Concerns about the use of rebates in this manner have been raised by many individuals, including FDA Chairman
* * *
23 Wehrwein, Peter. 2015. "A Conversation with
24 Plan sponsors are not simply looking for the lowest cost plan, but instead the plan that best balances costs and benefits for their customers or employees.
* * *
Given the potential for the rebates contingent on rival products to block potential entrants, regulators should consider more careful oversight and monitoring of rebate contracts that reference rivals. In situations where a large portion of the market is not contestable by the new entrant - for example, in the case of the first biosimilar entering against a reference product - it may be advisable for regulators to create additional restrictions on the ability of rebate contracts to reference the position of rival products on the formulary. In particular it may be necessary to consider separate rules or tests for contracts and rebates based on whether patients are treatment-naive or medically stable on a particular biologic product or biologic products.
In considering why government intervention may be necessary to address these contract structures, it is important to note that even if exclusive contracts limit entry and raise market wide prices, each PBM may have an incentive to demand a bid from a manufacturer for exclusive formulary placement. This could maximize the rebate for the PBM and allow for a more competitive PBM and/or health insurance product. Any individual PBM would benefit from such a contract and may not be able to influence the individual entry decision for any particular product. This could result in a "tragedy of the commons" problem that might be best solved by government action.
II.D. Creating Stronger Incentives for Negotiation in Government Programs
Supporting a competitive market for prescription drugs is made even more complicated by the heavy role of government in the procurement of healthcare for vulnerable populations such as the indigent, elderly, and disabled. Given the fact that healthcare is a unique product for which society places particular value on an individual's ability to access services regardless of their ability to pay, the
* * *
25 Liu, Yanchun. 2018. "FDA chief says pharmas use rebates to block biosimilar competition." MarketWatch.
26 Narasimhan, Vas. 2018. "Novartis CEO: How To Create Cheaper Alternatives To The Most Expensive Drugs." Forbes.
27
28
* * *
(Continues with Part 2 of 2)
* * *
Original text here: https://www.help.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Senate_Testimony_HELP_Garthwaite.pdf
Reports Outline Managed Care Study Findings from Rutgers University Cancer Institute of New Jersey (Association of Medicaid Expansion of the Affordable Care Act With Operations for Benign Endocrine Surgical Disease): Managed Care
Senate Health Committee Issues Testimony From Northwestern University Professor (Part 2 of 2)
Advisor News
Annuity News
Health/Employee Benefits News
Life Insurance News