Senate Health Committee Issues Testimony From Northwestern University Professor (Part 2 of 2)
* * *
(Continued from Part 1 of 2)
Given the economically meaningful role of the public sector in the healthcare market, the ability to maintain a competitive market inherently relies, at least in part, on government policies and regulations. Ultimately, healthcare is our nation's most meaningful public-private partnership. This has become even more apparent as
However, successfully managing these public-private partnerships requires establishing rules that enhance rather than inhibit competition. While the existing Medicare Part D program involves a large amount of price negotiation, there are still many drugs paid for by Medicare that effectively involve no direct price negotiation by a payer and instead attempt indirectly benefit from private market negotiations. These drugs are administered by providers and covered under the Medicare Part B benefit. Rather than use private firms to directly negotiate prices for these products, Medicare operates under a "buy and bill" system. Physicians purchase these drugs and then are reimbursed a fixed percentage above the average sales price (ASP) of the product - a price measure intended to account for rebates paid by manufacturers to payers. The purpose of this reimbursement system is to provide doctors with simplicity and predictability of reimbursement. These attractive features, however, come at a meaningful cost for the entire system, as the Part B procurement rules increase prices for the public and private markets while also shifting share at the margin to more expensive treatment options.
In order to understand the widespread effects of Part B, consider the motivations of a pharmaceutical manufacturer negotiating with PBMs and payers to determine its optimal price. Given that these firms are attempting to maximize profits, they set prices that are expected to earn the greatest profits. Once those profit-maximizing prices are set, higher prices will, by definition, decrease the firm's total profits. This occurs because the increased margin will not make up for the lost quantity (and related profits) that comes from a greater use of prior authorization, step therapy, increased cost sharing, or other utilization management tools.
* * *
29 Garthwaite, Craig. 2017. "Why replacing Obamacare is so hard: It's fundamentally conservative."
* * *
By linking public and private prices, the Part B purchasing rule distorts the optimal pricing decision in the private market. Firms are willing to increase private prices, and suffer declining profits in the private market, because they know they can make up those lost profits and more from the public market. In addition, because they know that physicians earn more money from administering a higher-priced drug, they have an additional incentive related to Part B for raising prices.
The combination of these factors means that the Part B procurement rules create the incentives for firms to offer fewer discounts in the private market, resulting in a higher ASP and greater profits from the public market. As a result, the current Part B rules for purchasing physician-administered drugs result in higher prices in both the public and the private markets. These incentives increase with Medicare's market share in each drug - a larger Medicare market means the potentially higher reimbursement from the public payers is more important for determining profits than the lost sales in the private market. Given the age and disease profile of Part B enrollees, there are a large number of high-cost drugs for which Medicare has a meaningfully large market.
As we look for policy solutions to address the lack of competition created by the Part B reimbursement rules, we must confront two areas of concern. Part B can cause higher prices both because physicians have an incentive to prescribe higher priced drugs (because they earn more for administering such products) and because manufacturers have an incentive to raise private prices to influence the public market.
In attempting to address physician incentives, we must be careful not to create perverse incentives to inappropriately prescribe lower-cost drugs. We also must be careful about creating a situation where it is no longer economically viable for physicians to practice in particular areas or in particular organizational forms. For example, attempts to reform the Part B procurement rules that switch to simply paying physicians a flat fee for each administered drug ignore the fact that physicians can face meaningful inventory costs for stocking and maintaining a large volume of high-cost drugs. Many of these costs are likely a function of the acquisition cost of the product. These costs could be particularly acute for small practices, which may lack sufficient liquidity to maintain sufficient stock of medications and may make prescription choices to limit these costs. At the extreme, this could push further consolidation of the provider market.
While there are many details to work out in this area, I would strongly encourage policymakers to follow the policy lead of Part D and find ways to utilize private-sector vendors to negotiate lower prices for Part B, rather than accepting this portion of Medicare as being a price taker. Failing to do so will continue to perpetuate a policy that increases spending across the system.
III. The role of government in supporting a robust small molecule generic market
As discussed above, the access-innovation trade off involves granting firms a time-limited period of market exclusivity. At the conclusion of this period, it is in the best interest of society for products to be sold in a robust and competitive market. Our existing system of follow-on competition has largely worked well since the passage of the Hatch-Waxman Act in 1984. However, the complexity of the modern drug market has created a new set of challenges for this previously well-functioning process.
Markets for generic small molecule products are intended to have fierce price competition facilitated by the automatic substitution of prescriptions towards less-expensive generic products. In a well-functioning generic market, firms compete primarily on price and therefore profits are determined by a firm's ability to manufacture products at the lowest marginal cost. This fierce price competition means that successful entrants must be able to produce enough to reach the minimum efficient scale (MES) of their production process. Absent sufficient quantity, entrants realize they will find themselves at a perpetual cost disadvantage to incumbent firms and therefore will rationally decline to enter the market. For sufficiently small markets, there is only enough demand for a single manufacturer to reach MES - and the incumbent firm is a natural monopolist that maintains meaningful pricing power.
In recent years, several firms appear to have recognized the pricing power available to ANDA holders for generic products with sufficiently small potential markets. This was perhaps best personified by the pricing strategies of
For some of these products, private firms are stepping forward with market-based solutions. Specifically, a consortium of hospitals led by
While vertical integration in this setting is an efficient response by hospitals in response to a market failure in their supplier market, CivicaRx will likely not find it valuable to undertake the manufacturing of products that are sold directly to patients through retail or specialty pharmacies or administered in an outpatient setting. Those products do not impact the financial health of the hospitals involved in the joint venture. Therefore, solutions for these other products must come from new government policies that either reduce the number of natural monopoly markets or use economic tools to more directly intervene in the natural monopoly markets that remain.
If high fixed entry costs make it difficult for multiple firms to profitably produce small-market generics, one potential policy solution is to lower these fixed costs. This would decrease the quantity required for a new entrant to reach MES and compete with the incumbent manufacturer. In recent years, the FDA has been focused on programs to accomplish this goal. For example, there have been efforts to streamline and harmonize the generic application process across developed countries.32 There have also been attempts to increase the speed and efficiency of the ANDA process, which would decrease barriers to entry and potentially increase the number of markets that could support multiple firms.33
* * *
30 Hopkins, Jared S., and
31 Abelson, Reed, and
* * *
I would encourage the FDA to continue to evaluate the approval process to look for additional efficiencies that would decrease entry costs. However, even the most efficient process for entering a generic market will require some expenditures to demonstrate the safety and bioequivalence of the product - and this will always represent a meaningful fixed-cost investment. Therefore, another potential solution to promote entry is to attempt to increase the size of some generic markets. While this can't be accomplished within any geographic boundary (i.e., we are unlikely to uncover more patients with these types of conditions), I would encourage
Even after efforts to decrease costs and increase market sizes, there likely will remain some markets that still cannot support multiple firms. In this case, further regulations are likely necessary to reach an efficient outcome. Senator
However, I fear that a government entity will likely fail at being an efficient producer of these products - after all, this is not an enterprise in which they specialize. As a result, the marginal costs of a government producer would likely be higher than for a private firm with experience in drug production. Before the government undertakes such a new and complicated economic activity, I would propose a private-sector solution in which
* * *
32 Gottlieb, Scott. 2018. "Advancing Toward the Goal of Global Approval for Generic Drugs: FDA Proposes Critical First Steps to Harmonize the Global Scientific and Technical Standards for Generic Drugs." FDA.
33 Elvidge, Suzanne. 2018. "FDA sets another record in 2018 for generic drug approvals." BioPharma Dive.
34
35 Warren, Elizabeth. 2018. "It's time to let the government manufacture generic drugs."
* * *
The exact specifics of such an exclusivity would need to be worked out, but a first step would be for
After establishing the market characteristics likely to lead to natural monopolies, I would propose the FDA be required to undertake a request for proposal (RFP) process for those markets. Under this RFP process, any private firm could apply for the rights to be the exclusive manufacturer of a natural monopoly generic medicine at a certain fixed percentage above manufacturing costs. As part of this RFP process, firms would compete on the amount of margin they would require to serve the market. The winning firm would possess the exclusive rights to sell the drug at this regulated price for a time period sufficient to recover the fixed costs of entry. At that time, the FDA would have the option of re-auctioning off the market exclusivity. In order to ensure the efficient operation of this process, it may also be necessary for the FDA to set a maximum percentage that they will accept before they will turn to a non-profit or government supplier for the product. This will limit any ability of firms to collude to divide up the markets they choose to enter.
* * *
36 Berndt, Ernst R.,
37 Silverman, Ed. 2019. "Here's how prosecutors say generic drug makers schemed to fix prices." STAT.
* * *
I would encourage
* * *
38 Chandra, Amitabh,
39 The problem of competition for precision medicine will be further complicated in situations where the patented product is a biologic product.
* * *
Original text here: https://www.help.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Senate_Testimony_HELP_Garthwaite.pdf
Senate Health Committee Issues Testimony From Northwestern University Professor (Part 1 of 2)
Audits find issues with 5 Westmoreland fire department relief associations [Tribune-Review, Greensburg, Pa.]
Advisor News
Annuity News
Health/Employee Benefits News
Life Insurance News