Overreaching on Obesity: Governments Consider New Taxes on Soda and Candy [Special Report (Tax Foundation)]
By Drenkard, Scott | |
Proquest LLC |
Introduction
In the past two decades nutritionists, biologists, and doctors have become increasingly interested in the causes and prevention of obesity. This fascination seems warranted; the incidence of obesity in adults jumped from 13 percent to 34 percent between 1962 and 2008, though it has since leveled off.1
Recently, this fervor has spilled over into the political scene as many politicians and some scientists make the case for government intervention to help trim the nation's waistline. This desire has taken the form of proposals for taxes on fast food, salt, and vending machines, as well as outright bans on specific substances like trans fats. Some of these measures have been successful, while others have failed.
This report reviews some of the common arguments for and against the unequal taxation of different food items with the aim of curbing obesity. As a part of the analysis, we present an in-depth, up-to-date look at the progress of this type of legislation at the state and federal level, and offer suggestions for better ways to fight the obesity problem while avoiding the myriad problems that arise from attempts to do so through the tax code.
Obesity: "I Know It When I See It"?
Over a century and a half later,
One of the most criticized aspects of BMI is that it makes no distinction between mass which is fat and mass which is muscle. As a result, the measure is not a good indicator of health risk.3 Often this means people who are in shape fall into the overweight or obese categories (see Table 2).
Many health professionals are urging researchers and doctors to start using waist measurements as a tool for analyzing patients' optimal weight.4 They say that while waist measurements also have drawbacks, they tend to give a better picture of weight- related health problems and are just as simple to collect as BMI figures.
Body Mass Index is the backbone of the data on obesity, and as we examine the case for obesity taxes, we will see that this flawed measurement technique can have profound effects on how economists and politicians attempt to set the tax rate on soda and candy.
What Is Candy?
Each state has a different definition of which products fall under the category of "candy" for the purposes of taxation, and these variations create complexity problems. These definitions are important because they determine which products will be taxed; this is known as the "base" of the sales tax. In
Singling out specific products to be excluded from or included in the sales tax base leads to a much more complex tax code, and the above definition of candy leads to tax compliance problems. Various snack bars have ingrethent combinations that appear to fit under this definition of candy, but from a brief survey of grocery stores, we have determined that many stores incorrectly treat certain products as food rather than as candy.
While the above represents an instance where products are considered candy when they probably would not be colloquially called candy, there are also cases where products that people generally call candy do not meet the legal definition. Chocolate bars that include any form of flour, like Kit-Kat® and Twix®, which have a cookie inside, are not candy under this definition and are therefore exempt from a targeted tax.
The Streamlined Sales Tax Governing Board, a voluntary coalition of several states which was founded in an attempt to bring some uniformity and simplicity to state sales tax bases,6 tried to address this definitional problem in August of 2010. They developed a six-page document outlining the proper definition of "candy," where they targeted the definition of "flour" for clarification:
For purposes of the definition of candy, "flour" does not include a product that can be called "flour" under the
These definitional contortions are necessary only because states treat products differently for sales tax purposes. Once a state has decided to treat candy differently from other groceries or other goods and services, this necessitates complex definitions and unequal treatment of specific products. Taxing all final retail sales equally and reducing rates overall could avoid these issues.8
What Is Soda?
Many states have hazy definitions of "soda" as well. In most states for the purposes of an excise tax (a tax levied on a specific product) sodas are officially called "caloric-sweetened beverages" or "soft drinks" and include some of the usual suspects like cola, root beer, ginger ale and lemon-lime carbonated drinks. But they also include any non-alcoholic beverage which is sweetened with a sucrose agent like sugar or high-fructose corn syrup.
Most states also tax powder or syrup used to make sugar-sweetened beverages. Since the tax is levied on a per-ounce basis, they tax it according to how much soda or beverage the powder or syrup yields. This can result in hefty taxes on popular drink mixes like lemonade (see Table 9).
In
In almost all states considering soda excise taxes, popular hydration drinks like Gatorade® and Vitamin Water® would be taxable under the proposed bills. The
Notably, in all the states that already have a soda excise tax -
The Frappuccino® Test
While most people can easily name some beverages that are considered "soft drinks," there are some surprising products that fall into this category. One example of the confusion over definitions is the case of bottled Frappuccino® beverages. Frappuccino® is often exempt because of its coffee content (
Most states exempt milk, baby formulas, weight loss beverages, medical food, coffee and tea. In
Soda and
In 2009, in an effort to find different ways to fund the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, federal lawmakers drew up plans for a national excise tax on soda. Though no specific rate was ever proposed, the
National soda and candy tax schemes have been tried before in
At this time, sweets were not being vilified as the culprit of an obesity pandemic, but instead were seen as a non-necessity, even a luxury, that people ought to pay more for to help the war effort. The "beverage" tax, which was levied on such dissimilar items as ice cream, egg creams, and ginger beer, was hard to collect. "The law says cold malted milk is a beverage and subject to tax," read a
Drug store owners formed the
Recent Proposals for Soda and
Table 5 shows tax rates on grocery products in the 50 states and the
This tax break does not extend to all products though. Seventeen of the states that exempt groceries from sales tax exclude candy from the "groceries" definition and tax it at the general sales tax rate. Twenty-two states and D.C. do the same for soda. Four states go even further and place an excise tax on soda:
In addition to collecting a 1.9 percent manufacturer's tax on soda,
However, not all new soda excise tax proposals would tax the sugary beverages based on volume. In the 2011 session,
While many states are proposing new excise taxes for soda and candy, other states that had them have voted them out of existence.
Many bills have been introduced repeatedly in recent years, despite unpopular reception. In
Other notable action for soda tax bills has been widespread. For example, a
This analysis suggests that excise taxes on soda and candy are an increasingly attractive source of revenue for tax collectors. With 22 states having recent experience with a soda excise tax in some form or another, the issue is likely to be an important legislative debate for years to come.
Four states -
The Externality Myth
People sometimes engage in actions that create side effects for others in the economy. These side effects are called "externalities," because they shift a cost or benefit of an action away from decision-makers and onto some external party. The classic example of an externality problem is a paper factory that expels fumes into the air while producing paper. While the company may enjoy the benefits of profits from their sale of paper, they shift some of the costs of paper production onto the rest of society in the form of increased pollution.24
Economists and policymakers sometimes support governmental intervention to correct for externality problems, but in the case of soda and candy taxation, the logic is flimsy. According to proponents of taxes on soda and candy, obese people create a negative externality because they get sick more often. Some estimate that obesity and overweight problems account for 9. 1 percent of all health care costs in the U.S. This amounts to
Therefore, proponents claim, taxpayers and insurance holders pay for the actions of obese people in the form of higher entitlement spending for
Of course, taxes on soda and candy would not reasonably address the obesity problem under these criteria. Instead of taxing obesity directly as mandated by economic theory, they would only tax potential causes of obesity in the form of candy and soda. In short, obese people may create an externality, but candy and soda do not necessarily do so. Some have said that if proponents of a soda tax really wanted to help internalize the social costs of obesity, they ought to tax obesity directly rather than tax arbitrarily chosen products like soda and candy. (Of course this would not be politically feasible or desireable.) In a tongue-and-cheek commentary,
If public health is the role of government, let's not get bogged down in this nonsense about rigging the relative prices of arugula and Ho-Hos. Let's just raise the price of being unhealthy. . . I modestly propose Americans be made to file an annual health audit with the
Furthermore, not all externalities signify market failure. The "cost shifting" caused by obesity seems to persist only as a result of government interference. In many cases, the only reason that an externality exists is because
In addition,
The problem with the externality argument is that, even if obesity raises health care costs of the obese, this externality should be corrected by having health insurers impose surcharges on obese insureds that reflect the additional costs. Few criticize surcharges imposed by auto insurance firms on drivers with drunk driving records, so why not correct for higher costs associated with obesity through insurance premiums? Unfortunately, federal health care legislation passed earlier this year severely reduces or eliminates differential health insurance pricing.27
Excise Taxes Often Fail to Produce Desired Behavior Changes
A careful reading of the literature on "sin taxes" suggests that not only do excise taxes have unintended consequences; they are often completely ineffective at bringing about the desired behavior change. Psychologist
Brownell cites many useful consumption figures in this article, but one very important statistic is misleading. While Brownell states that "between 1977 and 2002, the per capita intake of caloric beverages doubled in
Further, the exact impacts of excise taxation on individual behavior are still debated. Brownell's article uses elasticity analysis to claim that a
Economist
Furthermore, Fletcher's analysis concludes that when adolescents stop drinking soda due to price increases, the decrease in calories consumed is completely offset by increases in calories consumed from other beverages. This means that the "substitution effect" may very well be 100 percent, which is known as "perfect substitution," as children and adolescents tend to replace soda with juice drinks and milk as the price of soda rises. If anything, this could lead to weight gain, as some beverages have more calories than soda.32
Excise Taxes Often Have Unforeseen Negative Effects
Public policies often have unintended consequences that outweigh their benefits. In the case of cigarette taxation, some of the results are more far-flung than policymakers could have imagined.
Fleenor (2006) found that excessive cigarette taxes in
On the morning of
LaFaive and Nesbit (2010), found that smuggled cigarettes account for substantial portions of the cigarettes consumed in each state. In
Adda and Cornaglia (1996) have concluded that increases in the price of cigarettes due to excise taxes led smokers to select cigarettes with higher tar and nicotine content or just to change their behavior and smoke cigarettes more "intensely."36
It seems entirely plausible that a new type of drink could emerge from manipulation of soda prices. Under a new tax regime, we might see soda manufacturers advertise their brand as the highest in caffeine or sugar, in a sort of "more bang for your buck" approach. It seems equally likely that servings would get smaller and more concentrated to avoid taxation on a per-ounce basis. Energy drinks would likely become more popular.37
Politically Expethent, but Still Poor Tax Policy
Excise taxes are different from other taxes in that they have two goals: raise revenue and discourage consumption. This is a win-win for politicians, because after the fact, they can always claim success. If the tax is particularly bad at garnishing stable revenue, supporters are able to claim that the tax did a good job of discouraging behavior, and vice versa.
Surveys also suggest that soda taxes are only popular when coupled with some other favorable policy. A poll of New Yorkers showed that 66 percent of people oppose soda taxes in general, but when they are told the revenue will go toward health care costs, they respond differently: 49 percent oppose the bill and 48 percent support it.38
Not surprisingly, many of the soda tax bills currently under consideration would allocate part of the revenue for health care and education programs, some of which would have Orwellian names. In
Soda Tax Rates Could Increase to 264 Percent
While the proposed soda taxes in many states are levied at a "penny per ounce," it takes some effort to convert this into an easily understandable effective tax rate. Assuming pre-tax prices remain contant, a two liter bottle of store brand soda would be 68 percent more expensive under the new proposed bills. Store brand lemonade drink mix would see a price increase of 132 percent (see Table 8).
If the levy is set at
Throwing out the Baby with the Bath Water
Proponents of a soda excise tax claim that soda consumption is linked to obesity. In a 2007 meta-analysis of existing studies, Vartanian et al. conclude that soda intake is clearly linked to increased "energy" intake and body weight. In short, those who drink more soda tend to be more obese.40
That said, one can drink soda without being obese. Many people with a "healthy" Body Mass Index enjoy the occasional soda or candy bar - maybe even one per day - and do not become obese. They modify their calorie intake elsewhere, or balance their diet with more exercise. However, an excise tax on soda or candy punishes these people, too, which raises questions of equity within the tax code.
A point made by many economists that is often overlooked in the health literature is that any social welfare gains from soda and candy taxes reducing obesity would be offset by the welfare loss of higher taxes on non-obese soda drinkers. Setting the tax at an arbitrary rate (as appears to be the case in every state) makes it likely that society will be worse off as a result of the taxes.
Regressivity and Neutrality
The primary purpose of taxes is to raise revenue for necessary government services, not to change behavior. Therefore, the tax code should not discriminate against certain groups of people and favor others. Soda and candy taxes aim to change the behavior of obese people, but the consequences of soda taxation are more discriminatory than what first meets the eye.
Many people claim that taxes on soda and candy would be regressive, meaning that lower-income individuals would bear a disproportionate share of the tax burden, and we cannot know how a tax will affect each income group until it is instituted. We do know that people with lower incomes spend a larger portion of their earnings on groceries than people in higher income groups.41 Schurtleff (2009) found that the bottom quintile of income earners already pay the largest share of their income in excise taxes: 1.9 percent in 2006, compared to 0.4 percent for the top quintile.42
Simplicity and Stability
In addition to creating confusing definitional problems, excise taxes on a new product increase tax complexity because they require a new structure of collection that must be planned and executed by tax collection authorities. Adding new excise taxes on soda and candy, as opposed to changing current tax rates (which would require no new overhead), would increase tax agencies' administrative costs. An egregious example of this occurs in
Conclusion
Singling out soda and candy for taxation is a poor method of combating obesity. Proponents of obesity taxation argue that they are helping to internalize externalities, yet what they really do is unfairly burden all who enjoy soda and candy, regardless of what might be otherwise very healthy lifestyle habits.
Further, taxes like this tend to have unintended consequences. Detailed economic analysis shows that when the consumption of soda is discouraged with higher prices, children and adolescents tend to substitute other food or drink to make up for lost calories. Taxes on soda could even cause an increase in caloric consumption, as other substitutes can have higher calorie contents than soda.
The solution to the obesity problem will not come from abdicating personal decisions like eating choices to government. It will come from consumers making prudent decisions about their own diets, exercise and health needs.
Key Findings
* 17 states tax candy at a higher rate than other groceries, and four states collect an excise tax on soda.
* In 2011, 14 states proposed new soda taxes (in some cases, raising product prices by as much as 264 percent). Two states proposed new candy taxes.
* Between 1998 and 2010, soda consumption per capita fell by 16 percent.
* Soda and candy taxes do not necessarily decrease calorìe intake. One recent study finds that when adolescents switch away from soda due to price increases, the drop in calories is off et by an increase in calories consumed in other food and drink.
* Definitional problems pUgue the enforcement of and compliance with special taxes on candy and soda. For example, under many tax hws, a product with flour would be treated as food whik a simiUr product without flour would be considered candy.
* Excise taxes on candy and soda fall on all individuals who consume the products, even those who do so moderately.
The author would like to thank
Once a state has decided to treat candy differently from other groceries or other goods and services, this necessitates complex definitions and unequal treatment of specific products. Taxing all final retail sales equally and reducing rates overall could avoid these issues.
In the war against obesity, soda seems to be the first political target.
Economists and policymakers sometimes support governmental intervention to correct for externality problems, butin the case of soda and candy taxation, the logic is flimsy.
With 22 states having recent experience with a soda excise tax in some form or another, the issue is likely to be an important legisktive debate for years to come.
Tax or Fee?
Is a government-imposed charge on candy or soda a tax or a fee? In
American antipathy to taxes is deeply rooted in our nation's history following early experiences with the Tea Tax, Stamp Tax, and Whiskey Tax. Policymakers often seek to raise revenue in ways that will not result in the "tax hiker" label, even if it requires calling an obvious tax a "fee." Additionally, many states impose procedural requirements on taxes (such as supermajority thresholds, multiple readings, or voter approval) but not on fees.
The difference between taxes and fees is the way the revenue is used. Fees are charges paid by users for services provided by the government to those particular users and not to the general public. Examples include charges for sewer connections, entry into a state park, or obtaining a driver's license. Taxes, by contrast, are used to pay for services for everyone, not just those paying the charge. Examples include income and sales taxes, a gas tax whose revenue is used for road construction and maintenance, and the D. C. plastic bag tax, which dedicates its revenue to river cleanup.
These are not just different labels for identical revenue categories but rather two different models for government revenue. In both cases, a payer makes a voluntary decision to engage in an activity (earning income, buying gasoline, buying a plastic bag, entering a park) but in neither case is the charge itself voluntary. (A voluntary gift to government programs, which some state income tax forms allow, would be a donation.)
Most candy and soda tax proposals direct the revenue to general government spending, even if it is targeted for obesity prevention or health promotion. These activities are services available to the general population and are not provided specifically to the payers of the charge. Therefore, revenue raised by imposing a charge on candy or soda is properly called a tax.
Under a new tax regime, we might see soda manufacturers advertise their brandas the highest in caffeine or sugar, in a sort of "more bang for your buck" approach.
A two-liter bottle of store brand soda would be 68 percent more expensive under the proposed bilk. Store brand kmonade drink mix would see a price increase of 132 percent. If the levy is set at
Excise taxes are different from other taxes in that they have two goals: raise revenue and discourage consumption. This is a win-win for politicians, because after the fact, they can always claim success.
Proponents of obesity taxation argue that they are helping to internalize externalities, yet what they really do is unfairly burden all who enjoy soda and candy, regardless of what might be otherwise very healthy lifestyle habits.
The solution to the obesity problem will not come from abdicating personal decisions like eating choices to government. It will come from consumers making prudent decisions about their own diets, exercise and health needs.
1 Cynthia L.
2 Garabed Eknoyan, "Adolphe Quetelet (1796-1874) the average man and indices of obesity," Nephrology Dialysis TranspL·nta?on,
3 Gill M. Price, Ricardo Uauy, et al., "Weight, shape, and mortality risk in older persons: elevated waist-hip ratio, not high body mass index, is associated with a greater risk of death,"
4 D. C. Chan et al. "Waist circumference, waist-to-hip ratio and body mass index as predictors of adipose tissue compartments in men," QJiVl (2003) 96 (6): 441-447. http://qjmed.oxfordjournals.Org/content/96/6/44l.abstract
5 N.J. STAT. ANN. 54:32B-82(c) (West 2008); GAo. Rev. Stat. ? 39-26-707(1.5)(b),)(West 2010).
6
7 Strcamilned Sale. Tax Board For Augun26SLAC Thkconfrrence Rule 3276 Food end Food Ingndienr. Definidon. Augur 25, 2010 hrrp://wwwrrnmllnede.lestax.org/uploads/downloads/SLA%20.Meeting%20Materials/SL10046_Rule%20327%_%20_%Candy%20_%20Draft%20for%208_26_10%20SLAC%20 Teleconference pdf
8 SeeWilliam Ahern, "What~s Wrong with Calithrnials Sales Tax Exemption fin Groceries?" Tax Foundation Tax Policy Blog.
9 The Virginia tax docs not even provide a definition ot "sott drink" in its Administrative Code.
10 See H. R. 537, 107th Leg., 1st Reg. Sess. (Tenn. 201 1).
11 If not for the milk in Frappuccino®, it would be taxable in
12 Jane Adamy, "Soda Tax Weighed to Pay for Health Care." the
13 F.W.Taussig, "The War Tax Act of 1917,"
14 Roy G. Blakey and
15 Joseph J.
16 Roy G. Blakey and
17 Joseph J.
18
19 Susan M., "Voters strongly support beverage tax repeal,"
20
21 Adam Lynch, "Bashing Sodas and Saving Schools,"
22 H.R 1679, 2010 Leg., lólstSess. (NH. 2010)
23 Glenn Blain and
24 Bryan Caplan, "Externalities." The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. http://www.econub.org/library/Enc/Externalities.html
25 E.A.
26 Will Wilkinson, "Tax the Fat, Not Their Food," The Economist online.
27 Michael L.
28
29 Kelly Brownell, et al. "
30 John Sicher, ed. 'Top 10 CSD Results for 2010," Beverage Digest.
31 Jason Fletcher, et. al. "The Effects of Soft Drink Taxes on Child and Adolescent Consumption and Weight Outcomes. "
32 Ibid.
33 Scott Adams and
34 Patrick Fleenor, "California Schemin': Cigarette Tax Evasion and Crime in the Golden State." Tax Foundatton Special ReportNo. 145·
35 Michael LaFaive and
36 Jerome Adda and
37 This assertion is supported by the Alchian-Allen Theorem, which states diat as the price of two substitute products is increased by a fixed amount, consumption will flow to the higher quality product. See:
38 Bruce Drake, "Tax Sugary Drinks? New lforkers Say 'No' but
39 "State Gasoline Tax Rates, as of
40 Lenny R. Vartanian,
41
42 D. Sean Schurtleff, "Not So Sweet Excise Taxes. " Brief Analysis No. 663.
By
Analyst
Appendix
Enacted Soda Taxes:
W Va. Code § 11-19-1 (2010).
23 Va. Admin. Code § 10-390-20 et seq. (1985).
Va. Code Ann. § 58.1-1700 et seq. (1984).
Tenn. Code Ann. § 67-4-402 (1999).
006-05-203 Ark. Code R. § 203 (1993) (amended 2008).
Proposed Soda Taxes:
S. A. 1210, 2009-2010 Reg. Sess. (Ca. 2010).
A. B. 669, 2011-2012 Reg. Sess. (Ca. 2011).
H.R. 2214, 82d Leg., Reg. Sess. (Tex. 2011).
H. R. 537, 107th Leg., 1st Reg. Sess. (Tenn. 2011).
H.R. 5432, 2011 Leg., Jan. Sess. (R.I. 2011).
H.R. 2644, 7th Leg., Reg. Sess. (Or. 2011).
S. 396, 97th Gen. Assemb., Reg. Sess. (111. 2011).
S. 256, 2011 Leg., Jan. Sess. (Conn. 2011).
State Assemb. 669, 2011-2012 Leg., Reg. Sess. (CaI. 2011).
Vt. H. 151, 2011 Sess.
Ariz. H.B. 2643, 2011 Sess.
N.M. S.B. 288, 2011 Sess.
Miss. S.B. 2678, 2011 Sess.
Miss. H.B. 414, 2011 Sess.
Mont. H.B. ____ , 62nd Sess. (2011). (imposing a
Utah H.B. 426, 2011 Sess.
Hawaii H.B. 1188, 2011 Sess.
Hawaii H.B. 1062, 2011 Sess.
Hawaii H.B. 1216, 2011 Sess.
Hawaii H.B. 1179, 2011 Sess.
Proposed
Mass. H.B. 1697,2011 Sess.
Ore. S.J.R. 29., 2011 Sess.
Vt. H.B. 146, 2011 Sess.
Vt. H.B. 98, 2011 Sess.
N.Copyright: | (c) 2011 Tax Foundation Inc. |
Wordcount: | 6885 |
Avery Dennison Mourns Death of Charles D. Miller, Visionary Business Executive and Civic Leader
WHY PRIZE? THE SURPRISING RESURGENCE OF PRIZES TO STIMULATE INNOVATION [Research Technology Management]
Advisor News
Annuity News
Health/Employee Benefits News
Life Insurance News