Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland: 'Sticky Wages on the Layoff Margin'
The working paper was written by
Here are excerpts:
* * *
Abstract
We design and field an innovative survey of unemployment insurance (UI) recipients that yields new insights about wage stickiness on the layoff margin. Most UI recipients express a willingness to accept wage cuts of 5-10 percent to save their jobs, and one-third would accept a 25 percent cut. Yet worker-employer discussions about cuts in pay, benefits, or hours in lieu of layoffs are exceedingly rare. When asked why employers don't raise the possibility of job-preserving pay cuts, four-in-ten UI recipients don't know. Sixteen percent say cuts would undermine morale or lead the best workers to quit, and 39 percent don't think wage cuts would save their jobs. For those who lost union jobs, 45 percent say contractual restrictions prevent wage cuts. Among those on permanent layoff who reject our hypothetical pay cuts, half say they have better outside options, and 38 percent regard the proposed pay cut as insulting. Our results suggest that wage cuts acceptable to both worker and employer could potentially prevent a quarter of the layoffs in our sample. We draw on our findings and other evidence to assess theories of wage stickiness and its role in layoffs.
* * *
1 Introduction
We design and field an innovative survey of unemployment insurance (UI) recipients that yields new insights about wage rigidity on the layoff margin. Specifically, we ask new UI recipients about their willingness to accept wage cuts to save their lost jobs, whether they had discussions with their former employers about compensation cuts in lieu of job loss, and, if not, why not. Our survey went to field in the state of
Most UI recipients in our sample express a willingness to accept wage cuts of 5-10 percent to save their lost jobs, and one-third are willing to take a 25 percent cut. Yet worker-employer discussions about cuts in pay, benefits, or hours to prevent layoffs almost never happen.
When asked why, nearly four-in-ten UI recipients do not know. Thirty-nine percent think wage cuts would not save their jobs, and 16 percent say pay cuts would undermine morale or lead the best workers to quit. For those who lost union jobs, 45 percent say contractual restrictions prevent wage cuts. Our results suggest that wage cuts acceptable to both the job loser and the former employer could potentially prevent about a quarter of the layoffs.
When UI recipients refuse our proposed wage cuts to save their jobs, we ask why. Among those who experienced permanent layoffs (four-fifths of our sample), half point to better outside options, 38 percent regard the proposed pay cut as insulting, and one-fifth prefer unemployment to working at the lower wage. Among those on temporary layoff, the most common reason for refusing a hypothetical wage cut is fear it might become permanent.
Our finding that employers do not offer pay cuts in lieu of layoffs is broadly consistent with evidence from employer surveys.1 While we draw inspiration from these studies, our worker-side survey offers distinct insights and advantages. First, it reveals that most new UI recipients would accept wage cuts in lieu of layoffs, and many are open to large wage cuts.
Employers' reluctance to offer wage cuts becomes more puzzling in the face of widespread workers' willingness to accept them. Second, our survey approach lets us explore workers' perceptions about why employers do not offer pay cuts to save jobs. Many simply do not know. Third, employer-side surveys of wage-setting behavior typically involve small samples compiled by cold calling firms and snowball sampling. (Bertheau et al., 2022, is a notable exception.) In contrast, our sample frame is precisely defined, and our sample design lends itself to a systematic, institutionalized approach with ongoing surveys.
To our knowledge, we are the first to document the disjunction between worker-side openness to wage cuts and a pervasive unwillingness of employers to even broach the subject.
We can discard a few possible explanations for this disjunction. First, less than 3 percent...
1 See, for example, Kaufman (1984), Blinder and Choi (1990), Agell and Lundborg (1995),
* * *
...of respondents point to minimum wage and benefit laws to explain why discussions about compensation cuts don't happen. Moreover, only 4 percent report an hourly pay rate on their lost job less than 1.05 times the legal minimum. Second, we ask specifically about lower pay for 12 months to save the lost job. Thus, worker-side openness to wage cuts does not reflect an intention to seek and quickly take a better-paying job. Third, job losers in our sample seldom experience pay cuts in the months leading up to layoffs. That is, we see almost no indication that employers try job-saving wage cuts before resorting to layoffs.
By targeting UI recipients, our sample frame and survey data let us develop new insights about sticky wages on the layoff margin. If sticky wages cause some workers to lose jobs and obtain UI benefits, our frame captures them. On the flip side, our frame selects against employment relationships that survive negative shocks by virtue of downward wage adjustments. Thus, we cannot use our sample to quantify the incidence of job-preserving downward wage adjustments. That said, very few job losers report discussions about compensation cuts to prevent layoffs--irrespective of industry, union status, tenure on the lost job, firm size, and other observables. If employer-worker discussions about wage cuts to save jobs were common, we would expect those discussions to succeed in some instances and fail in others. The failures would show up in our sample. That so few do indicates that discussions about job-preserving wage cuts rarely happen.
The rarity of employer-worker discussions about pay cuts in lieu of layoffs sits uneasily with theories that stress private information about outside options as a source of wage stickiness and privately inefficient layoffs. These theories lead us to anticipate efforts to overcome informational impediments to the preservation of valuable matches. That we see so few instances of such efforts raises a challenge for these theories, which we put in the form of a question: If private information leads to the dissolution of valuable matches, why don't employers (and workers) make greater efforts to overcome informational asymmetries?
To our knowledge, theoretical work has not addressed this challenge. Nor are we aware of empirical research on the issue.
The next section expands on the motivation for our study. Section 3 describes our survey, reports summary statistics, and offers evidence on the quality of the survey data. Section 4 documents the willingness of UI recipients to accept job-preserving wage cuts and the dearth of discussions about pay cuts to save jobs. Section 5 explores workers' perceptions about the reasons for sticky wages on the layoff margin and why many job losers refuse wage cuts.
Section 5 also quantifies the share of layoffs that could be avoided by wage cuts that are acceptable to the job loser and his or her former employer. Section 6 discusses our findings in relationship to the literature and draws some additional lessons from case studies. Section 7 offers concluding remarks.
* * *
References
Agell, Jonas and Per Lundborg (1995). ''Theories of Pay and Unemployment: Survey Evidence from Swedish Manufacturing Firms.''
Akerlof, George A (1982). ''Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange.''
Akerlof, George A.,
Akerlof, George A. and
Babeck'y, Jan,
Barro, Robert J. (1977). ''Long-Term Contracting, Sticky Prices, and Monetary Policy.''
Barwell, Richard D. and
Basu, Susanto and
Bauer, Thomas,
Becker, Gary S. (1962). ''Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis.''
Bertheau, Antoine, Marianna Kudlyak,
Bewley, Truman F. (1999). Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession.
Blanchard, Olivier and
Blank, Rebecca M. and
Blinder, Alan S. and
BLS (2019). ''Labor Force Statistics from the
Bulow, Jeremy I. and
Cahuc, Pierre,
Card, David (1990). ''Unexpected Inflation, Real Wages, and Employment Determination in Union Contracts.'' American Economic Review, 80(4), pp. 669--688. URL https: //www.jstor.org/stable/2006702.
Card, David and
Christiano, Lawrence J.,
Couch, Kenneth A. and
Curtin, Richard,
Davis, Steven J. (2011). ''Job Search, Emotional Well-Being, and Job Finding in a Period of Mass Unemployment: Evidence from High-Frequency Longitudinal Data: Comment.'' Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 42(1), pp. 58--70. URL https://www.jstor.org/ stable/41228523.
Davis, Steven J. and
Devicienti, Francesco,
Dickens, William T.,
Ehrlich, Gabriel and
Elsby, Michael W. L. (2009). ''Evaluating the Economic Significance of Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity.''
Elsby, Michael W. L.,
Elsby, Michael W. L. and
Fallick, Bruce,
Fehr, Ernst and
Fischer, Stanley (1977). ''Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule.''
Freeman, Richard and
Ganong, Peter,
Gray, Jo Anna (1976). ''Wage Indexation: A Macroeconomic Approach.''
Grigsby, John,
Hall, Robert E. (2005). ''Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness.'' American Economic Review, 95(1), pp. 50--65. doi:10.1257/0002828053828482.
Hall, Robert E. and
Hazell, Jonathon,
Hirsch, Barry T. and
IDES (2017). ''Unemployment Insurance Benefits Handbook.'' URL https://www2.illinois. gov/ides/IDESFormsandPublications/CLI105L.pdf, accessed: 11/4/2019.
Jacobson, Louis S.,
J~ager, Simon,
Jardim, Ekaterina S.,
Kahn, Shulamit (1997). ''Evidence of Nominal Wage Stickiness from
Kahneman, Daniel,
Kaufman, Roger T. (1984). ''On Wage Stickiness in
Kaur, Supreet (2019). ''Nominal Wage Rigidity in Village Labor Markets.'' American Economic Review, 109(10), pp. 3585--3616. doi:10.1257/aer.20141625.
Keynes,
Kimball, Miles and
Krolikowski, Pawel (2018). ''Choosing a
Krueger, Alan B. and
Krueger, Alan B. and
Krueger, Alan B. and
Kube, Sebastian,
Kudlyak, Marianna (2014). ''The Cyclicality of the User Cost of Labor.''
Kurmann, Andr'e and
Lachowska, Marta,
Leduc, Sylvain and
Lee, Darin and
Lewis,
Lindbeck, Assar and
MacLeod,
Malcomson, James M. (1997). ''Contracts, Hold-Up, and Labor Markets.''
Mas, Alexandre (2006). ''Pay, Reference Points, and Police Performance.''
McLaughlin, Kenneth J. (1990). ''General Productivity Growth in a Theory of Quits and Layoffs.''
McLaughlin, Kenneth J. (1991). ''A Theory of Quits and Layoffs with Efficient Turnover.''
McLaughlin, Kenneth J. (1994). ''Rigid Wages?''
Michaillat, Pascal (2012). ''Do Matching Frictions Explain Unemployment? Not in Bad Times.'' American Economic Review, 102(4), pp. 1721--1750. doi:10.1257/aer.102.4.1721.
Murray, Seth (2021). ''Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity's Effect on Employment Through
Nickell, Stephen and
Sandvik, Jason,
Schmitt-Groh'e, Stephanie and Mart'in Uribe (2013). ''Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity and the Case for Temporary Inflation in the
Schmitt-Groh'e, Stephanie and Mart'in Uribe (2016). ''Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity, Currency Pegs, and Involuntary Unemployment.''
Shimer, Robert (2004). ''The Consequences of Rigid Wages in Search Models.''
Smets, Frank and
Smith, Jennifer C. (2000). ''Nominal Wage Rigidity in the
Stansbury, Anna and
Taylor, John B. (1980). ''Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts.''
Taylor, John B. (1999). ''Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics.'' In
Tobin, James (1972). ''Inflation and Unemployment.'' American Economic Review, 62(1/2), pp. 1--18. URL http://www.jstor.org/stable/1821468.
Weiss, Andrew (1990). Efficiency Wages: Models of Unemployment, Layoffs and Wage Dispersion.
Woodford, Michael (2003). Money, Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy.
* * *
Citation: Davis, Steven J. and
* * *
The white paper is posted at: https://www.clevelandfed.org/-/media/project/clevelandfedtenant/clevelandfedsite/publications/working-papers/2023/wp2312.pdf
Investigators from University of International Business and Economics Release New Data on Finance (Exploring the Effect of Policies On Environmental Pollution Liability Insurance In China’s Highly Polluting Industries: Applying Ajzen’s Theory …): Business – Finance
Reports Outline Health Insurance Study Findings from University of Southern California (The value of Medicare coverage on depressive symptoms among older immigrants): Health Insurance
Advisor News
Annuity News
Health/Employee Benefits News
Life Insurance News