House Judiciary Subcommittee Issues Testimony From FTC Commissioner Wilson
* * *
Thank you for the opportunity to testify. In recent years, this Committee has played a pivotal role in spurring a rich dialogue on our antitrust laws.
It is an honor to appear before you today.
In my opening remarks, I will first provide context for the monopsony and labor issues we will discuss today. Then, I will address antitrust enforcement and proposals that impact labor markets, including occupational licensing, monopsony, and non-compete and no-poach agreements. These issues are important, and worthy of the time we are devoting to them today.
Finally, I will briefly touch on procedural irregularities at the
The Big Picture
The
Periodically, given the time that has passed since their enactment, commentators question whether those Acts remain capable of addressing issues that arise in new industries and dynamic markets. This question was asked in the 1990s when commentators wondered whether the antitrust laws were suited to address rapidly evolving technology markets. The D.C. Circuit made clear in the Microsoft case that the antitrust laws were sufficiently flexible to support a holding that the dominant technology firm of that time had violated the antitrust laws.1
The term 'new economy' can describe a diverse array of markets in which new information, communication, and other technologies have produced significant changes in recent decades. For purposes of this Report, the key question is whether antitrust analysis can properly account for the economic characteristics of these markets. Those characteristics include innovation, intellectual property, and technological change.2
Following an extensive inquiry, the
Commenters and witnesses largely agree that antitrust analysis has sufficient grounding in solid economic analysis, openness to new economic learning, and flexibility to enable the courts and the agencies properly to assess competitive issues in new economy industries. Most importantly, commenters noted, the economic principles on which antitrust is based do not require revision for application to those industries. As one economist [
In other words, previous periods of reflection have concluded that the antitrust laws are sufficiently broad and flexible to address the issues of the day, including rapidly evolving tech markets.
In recent years, the same question again has arisen: are our antitrust laws capable of addressing the concerns that have been raised about so-called Big Tech? This time, though, the discussion differs in notable ways.
First, while antitrust issues contribute to this question, the concerns about Big Tech are many and varied. Some observers are concerned about the seemingly limitless collection of consumer data by tech platforms, and the ways in which those data are used, shared, and monetized. Others are concerned about content curation and censorship. And still others are concerned about traditional antitrust issues, including serial acquisitions by large tech companies and refusals to deal with competitors.
Each of these concerns is worthy of discussion. But just because we hold the hammer of antitrust law in our hands does not mean we should treat every concern as a nail, lest we risk bludgeoning our entire economy. The better approach is to disaggregate the varied concerns about the tech sector and address each concern with the appropriate tools. For example, privacy concerns require federal privacy legislation, which I heartily support. And
That leaves the competition concerns. I believe the antitrust laws as currently written are sufficiently broad and flexible to address the competition issues in the dynamic and rapidly evolving tech sector. As noted above, the
The second way in which today's iteration of the question differs is this: the doubts that have been raised about the adequacy of our antitrust laws are not limited to dynamic and rapidly evolving markets. Instead, would-be reformers propose sweeping changes to our antitrust laws that would result in a fundamental transformation of our economy. The breadth of their aspirations is confirmed by the sweeping range of topics covered in
To be clear, the issues we will discuss today are important ones. But we should keep two points in mind during this discussion. First, the antitrust laws as they exist today embody concepts like monopsony and prohibit anticompetitive agreements like no-poach agreements and unreasonable non-competes. Second, antitrust enforcement as it exists today supports challenges to anticompetitive conduct that harms labor, middlemen, and other entities beyond the end consumer.
I am deeply troubled by proposals to replace modern antitrust enforcement and market forces with government micromanagement. Attempting to regulate the economy into competition, instead of engaging in antitrust enforcement based on sound economic principles, has harmed Americans in the past.12 This approach will undermine the American economy at the very moment it is struggling to recover from the COVID-19 pandemic. In addition, abandoning fact-based enforcement and sound economic principles for a highly interventionist competition policy that picks winners and losers will create incentives for rent-seeking and regulatory gamesmanship instead of competition and innovation. This result will harm everyone, including American labor.
Today's Antitrust Standards Address Monopsony and Labor Issues
I will discuss occupational licensing, monopsony, and non-compete and no-poach agreements in turn.
States have a legitimate interest in protecting the health, safety, and welfare of their residents, and occupational licensing regimes may help advance these goals. But all too frequently, occupational licensing regimes are used by incumbents - those already licensed in a state - to erect barriers to entry and insulate themselves from competition.13 Rent-seeking by incumbents limits consumer choice, drives up prices, and may decrease quality.14
The
In addition to bringing enforcement actions, the
The
Developments during the COVID-19 pandemic demonstrated that easing restrictions on occupational licensing can increase the availability of professionals to the benefit of consumers.
In particular, the pandemic highlighted the pitfalls of occupational licensing regimes that restrict the mobility of medical professionals and preclude them from providing services within their scope of medical expertise. Both state and federal agencies waived or repealed regulations that constrained the mobility and supply of health care professionals, reducing delays and restrictions on the availability of care.20
It was gratifying to see these changes, although unfortunate that a global pandemic was necessary to prompt them. As a society, we can choose to focus on the positive and preserve, even after the pandemic subsides, the enhanced levels of choice and competition in health care now emerging. Legislators and regulators should consider which laws and rules are truly necessary for patients' safety, and which ones create unnecessary barriers to market entry.
Specifically, changes made to address COVID-19 give policymakers the opportunity to observe how the absence of these restraints has impacted patients. Moreover, the fact that states have responded differently during the pandemic will enable comparative analyses, highlighting the benefit of states as laboratories of democracy.
Monopsony Resulting From Mergers or Collusive Agreements
A monopoly arises when a market has only one seller but many buyers; conversely, a monopsony arises when a market has many sellers but only one buyer.21 Both the
In the merger context, the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines devote a section to explaining that "[m]ergers of competing buyers can enhance market power on the buying side of the market, just as mergers of competing sellers can enhance market power on the selling side of the market."23 Notably, the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines provide that monopsony concerns may arise "even if the merger will not lead to any increase in the price charged by the merged firm for its output."24
Applying the Guidelines, the antitrust agencies examine proposed mergers to identify potential monopsony issues. For instance, the
Also applying the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, the
Agency challenges premised on monopsony concerns are not limited to mergers. For instance, in 2018, the
Non-Compete Provisions
Non-compete agreements that are unreasonable as to temporal length, subject matter, and/or geographic scope will be found to violate both federal36 and state antitrust laws.
Moreover, state and common law provide rich guidance on this topic. And to date, the economic evidence regarding the impact of non-competes in the labor arena is mixed. For these reasons, I believe we should heed the wise guidance of
Studies analyzing the impact of non-competes in the labor arena have revealed mixed results. Some studies have found that non-competes suppress employee wages and mobility. For example, one study found that a ban on non-competes for technology workers increased mobility by 11 percent and new-hire wages by four percent.38 Another study concluded that moving from the 10th to the 90th percentile in enforceability on non-competes decreased earnings by three to four percent.39 For low-wage workers, the group that has received the most attention,40
Other studies have found that non-competes have a beneficial impact on employee wages and other employee benefits. For example, one study concluded that physicians who sign noncompetes tend to earn more money.42 Another study found that non-competes increase incentives for firm-sponsored employee training.43 And other research has revealed that employee awareness of non-competes before offers are accepted generates higher wages relative to employees without non-competes.44
It is also important to consider the impact of non-competes on stakeholders other than employees. Non-compete agreements can facilitate innovation by assuring firms that trade secrets and other firm know-how will not be transferred to a rival.45 One study compared high and low non-compete enforceability regimes and concluded that enforceability facilitates riskier research and development investments.46 Another study of financial advisors found that ending enforcement of non-competes lowered prices to consumers, but also led to a larger than 40 percent increase in incidents of misconduct because firms were more reluctant to discipline advisors.47 Non-competes can also help firms and workers match more appropriately based on separation costs.48
States have or are moving to adopt laws in this area. In California,49 North Dakota,50 and Oklahoma,51 non-competes are prohibited. And several states have considered or passed legislation that limit non-competes for certain types of employees (e.g., Hawaii,52 New Mexico,53 and Oregon54). Many states are considering bills or adjusting already passed legislation to address employee non-competes.55
Despite mixed evidence on the impact of non-competes and the growing number of states with not just common law but legislation, some commentators continue to advocate for a federal solution. They assert that even when non-competes violate state law, employees who cannot afford a lawyer may experience an in terrorem effect.56 But state attorneys general are wellpositioned to take an active role in this arena, as the
As
No-Poach Agreements
Antitrust laws prohibiting price-fixing and market allocation apply to labor markets, including no-poach and similar agreements among competitors to constrain labor. Guidance published jointly by the
In 2016, the
Beyond clear warnings to the business community, the federal antitrust agencies have a history of challenging no-poach and related agreements that harm labor. The
fashion shows for attempting to reduce the fees and other terms of compensation for models.64 In 2007, the
More recently, in 2018, the
State attorneys general have also played a key role in challenging unlawful no-poach agreements. Notably,
Procedural Irregularities at FTC Preclude Robust Dialogue on
The issues that we are discussing today, together with other antitrust reforms under consideration, merit a thoughtful discussion. Traditionally, the
* Muzzling staff internally and externally;74
* Stifling the flow of agency records and information from staff to the Commission;75
* Largely abandoning the tradition of comprehensive staff recommendations discussing legal and economic issues, prudential considerations and litigation risks for matters before the Commission;76
* Giving minimal notice to Commissioners (and the public) of sweeping policy changes;77
* Giving no written explanations for sweeping policy changes until after those changes are implemented;78
* Evading meaningful dialogue at the Commission level;79
* Voting against notice and comment on major policy changes;80 and
* Short-circuiting public input by adopting policy statements during ongoing rulemakings that address precisely the topics at issue.81
These major changes represent a departure from decades of tradition at the agency. The result?
* Stakeholders are deprived of clarity and guidance regarding the
* The
* The majority is making fundamental substantive errors in areas in which the Commission supposedly holds expertise.86 In other words, faulty processes lead to substantive mistakes.
* The
Unfortunately, I fear that our successors at the agency will have a terrible time restoring the agency's reputation with
In closing, I thank the Committee for this opportunity to testify, and look forward to answering any questions you may have.
* * *
The footnotes can be viewed at: https://docs.house.gov/meetings/JU/JU05/20210928/114057/HHRG-117-JU05-Wstate-WilsonC-20210928.pdf
Center on Budget & Policy Priorities: Eliminating Structural Barriers Can Improve Latino People's Access to Health Coverage
N.Y. State Association of Counties: Rensselaer County Receives Risk Management Award
Advisor News
Annuity News
Health/Employee Benefits News
Life Insurance News